class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide .title[ # EC 380: Lecture 17 ] .subtitle[ ## Global Finance: Exchange Rates SR-Med ] .author[ ### Philip Economides ] .date[ ### Winter 2024 ] --- class: inverse, middle <style type="text/css"> @media print { .has-continuation { display: block !important; } } .pull-lefter { float: left; width: 67%; } .pull-rightish { float: right; width: 25%; } .pull-rightish ~ p { clear: both; } </style> # Prologue --- # Recap * Exchange rates determine price of foreign goods * Numerous reasons to hold foreign reserves * Shifts in exchange rates often mirror changes in demand and supply of currencies * PPP holds only in LR ### Today * SR, Medium exchange rates and ExR Systems --- # Topics <br> * Reasons for holding foreign reserves, main institutions * Effect of `\(\Delta S, \Delta D\)` of foreign currency on home currency * __Identify short, medium and long term forces that affect currency value__ * Three rules of gold standard * Compare and contrast various exchange rate systems * Price changes and real exchange rate interactions * List conditions necessary to form single currency area --- # FX Market: Flexible <img src="17-ExR_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-2-1.svg" width="95%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # FX Market: Flexible --- # FX Market: Flexible Decreased demand for GBP in USA (D2 `\(\leftarrow\)` D1) <img src="17-ExR_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-3-1.svg" width="85%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # FX Market: Medium Run <br> Usually a 4-5 year range, where countries experience ebbs and flows of .hi-pink[business cycle] booms and busts. -- During boom periods, incomes tick up, .hi-pink[aggregate demand rises] across consumers -- Some of that spills over into .hi-pink[increased demand for imports]. -- This implies a greater need for foreign currency. --- # FX Market: Medium Run Increased demand for GBP in USA (D1 `\(\rightarrow\)` D2) <img src="17-ExR_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-4-1.svg" width="85%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # FX Market: Medium Run Suppose UK sees economic boom, increased import of US goods, higher GBP reserves (S1 `\(\rightarrow\)` S2) <img src="17-ExR_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-5-1.svg" width="85%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # FX Market: Short Run Short run is a time period of one year or less. -- We observe continuous day-to-day fluctuations in exchange rates. <img src="17-ExR_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-6-1.svg" width="75%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # FX Market: Short Run <br> .hi-pink[What causes short run changes in ExR?] -- * Interest rate adjustments, which can occur 4-5 times in a year. -- * Speculation, driven by exogenous shocks to the state of the economy (e.g. political scandal in Brazil, discovery of natural gas deposits off Cypriot coast, COVID outbreak at Chinese ports) <br> This latter cohort contribute to a mechanism known as .hi-pink[price discovery] in exchange rates. --- # FX Market: Short <br> > Price discovery is the trial-and-error process of discovering the equilibrium price in a market. If speculators believe a currency is overvalued, they sell that currency, driving its value down. If correct, currency moves towards equilibrium and speculators are rewarded through arbitrage profits. -- If wrong, large losses are realized. This can often lead to bankruptcy if these risks were taken based on borrowed funds. -- .hi-pink[These stakes deliver a strong incentive to make the correct decision, bolstering the speed of market adjustments in the process.] --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> .hi-pink[Interest Parity Condition]: Difference between the home and foreign interest rates should be equal to the expected change (appreciation or depreciation) of the exchange rate. -- <br> `$$i-i^* = \frac{\left(F-R\right)}{R}$$` <br> where `\(i\)` is the home interest rate, `\(i^*\)` is the foreign interest rate, `\(F\)` is expected future exchange rate and `\(R\)` is the current exchange rate. --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> Suppose an investor has the choice to either invest locally or abroad in one-year bonds. -- > X year bond: After maturing for X year, the bond is paid back to the investor in full principal amount and includes a yield of interest accrued for X year(x) -- Respective rates of return are `\(i=0.03\)` and `\(i^*=0.02\)`. Each payoff is in a different currency. -- Suppose the 1-year US bond has a price of 1000 USD. --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> The bond's payoff is equal to `$$\text{P}\times(1+i)^n$$` where `\(P\)` is the principal amount invested, `\(i\)` is the interest rate and `\(n\)` represents the number of years the bond accrues interest for before maturing. -- `$$\text{US bond} = 1000 \times (1.03)^1 = 1030 \ \text{USD}$$` -- .hi-pink[German bond requires careful thoughts]. --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> Bond principal plus __2% interest__ is paid in euros. -- The dollar value of this investment choice depends on the .hi-pink[future exchange rate one year from now]. -- Suppose exchange rate today is __1.2 USD per EUR__. -- Investor can buy __833.33 EUR__ in exchange for __1000 USD__. <br> `$$\text{EUR bond} = 833.33 \times (1.02)^1 = 850 \ \text{EUR}$$` --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> To accurately compare the two choices, investor must .hi-pink[forecast the exchange rate] in one years time (F). -- If `\(E(F)=1.3 \ \text{USD/EUR}\)`, implies expected foreign value of `\(850 \times 1.3 = 1105 \ \text{USD}\)` -- US Bond worth `\(1030\)`, so foreign return of `\(1105\)` is more profitable. -- Expect return of foreign investment: `\(i' = \left[\frac{E(F)}{R}\times (1+i^*)\right]-1\)` .hi-pink[Compare i and i' to decide investment!] --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> To guarantee `\(E(F) = F\)` is to remove uncertainty from the setting. -- Hedge against exchange rate risk by signing contracts on the .hi-pink[forward exchange rate market.] -- Today's spot rate `\(R\)` and market rate on one year exchanges `\(F\)` indicate where market sees ExR moving in one year. -- If `\(F>R\)`, the currency is expected to depreciate. -- If `\(F<R\)`, the currency is expected to appreciate. --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> In our example, investors were willing to sell off US bonds in order to purchase foreign bonds. -- Funds will flow from the US to Germany, causing German money supply to rise. -- A greater money supply implies lower interest rates, so `\(i*\)` falls. -- Demand for German currency used to buy the bonds rises, so `\(R\)` rises. -- Market moves towards interest rate parity `\(i - i^* = \frac{\left(F-R\right)}{R}\)` --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> .hi-pink[What happens when F changes?] The future dollar value of German bonds in USD changes too. -- The scale and direction of the change dictate the choice investors make. -- Let us return to our previous example to see this in action. --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <table class="table" style="font-size: 14px; margin-left: auto; margin-right: auto;"> <thead> <tr> <th style="text-align:right;"> US bond, USD </th> <th style="text-align:right;"> German bond, EUR </th> <th style="text-align:right;"> F (USD per EUR) </th> <th style="text-align:right;"> German bond, USD </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> Purchase </th> </tr> </thead> <tbody> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 0.7 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 595 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> US </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 0.8 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 680 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> US </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 0.9 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 765 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> US </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.0 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> US </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.1 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 935 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> US </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.2 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1020 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> US </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.3 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1105 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> German </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.4 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1190 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> German </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.5 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1275 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> German </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.6 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1360 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> German </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.7 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1445 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> German </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.8 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1530 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> German </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1030 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 850 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1.9 </td> <td style="text-align:right;"> 1615 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> German </td> </tr> </tbody> </table> --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> Suppose `\(i<i^*\)` and `\(F<R\)`. US yields are lower and world expects USD to appreciate. -- Fed decides to set `\(i\)` equal to `\(i^*\)`. Increased returns on US bonds .hi-pink[(Foreign Reserves rise)]. -- Implies US foreign currency supply increases _(shifts right)_ from `\(S1\)` to `\(S2\)`. -- Demand for foreign bonds falls, shifts demand down _(shifts left)_ from `\(D1\)` to `\(D2\)`. -- Think of GBP market, expect USD to .hi-pink[appreciate] under these conditions. --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> These mechanisms playout somewhat like a .hi-pink[self-fulfilling prophecy]. -- If investors think USD will depreciate in future, `\(F\)` rises. -- This causes return on foreign bonds to improve, causing demand on foreign currency to rise and the dollar's spot rate `\(R\)` depreciates. -- <br> .hi-pink[A change in expectations about future exchange rates can lead to a similar change in the spot rate]. --- # FX Market: Interest Parity <br> We can think about the market playing out in two manners: -- 1) Covered interest parity (CIP) > Assume the investor has .hi-pink[perfect foresight] such that `\(E(F)=F\)`. -- 2) Uncovered interest parity (UIP) > Assume investor accepts risk involved and purchases with E(F) in mind. --- # FX Market: CIP <br> -- Investors will trade until returns from either bond equalize, and .hi-pink[all arbitrage opportunities are exhausted]. -- `$$\text{CIP}: (1+i) = (1+i^*)\frac{F_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}{R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}$$` -- In that case, investors are .hi-pink[indifferent] between either bond since their real returns are the same. -- Allows us to pin down the `\(F\)` necessary to achieve CIP `$$F_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}} = R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}} \frac{1+i}{1+i^*}$$` --- # FX Market: UIP This alternative method of investment allows us to determine how spot rates are established. -- The no-arbitrage condition for UIP is written as follows: `$$\text{UIP}: (1+i) = (1+i^*)\frac{E(F)_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}{R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}$$` -- Allows us to pin down the `\(R\)` necessary to satisfy UIP `$$R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}} = E(F)_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}} \frac{1+i^*}{1+i}$$` -- We can calculate today's spot rate if we know market expected exchange rate and these two respective interest rates. --- # Evidence of UIP <br> Taking both our previous equations, and dividing one into the other on __both sides__. `$$\text{CIP}: (1+i) = (1+i^*)\frac{F_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}{R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}\\ \text{UIP}: (1+i) = (1+i^*)\frac{E(F)_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}{R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}},\\ \implies 1 = \frac{F_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}{E(F)_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}$$` -- Under the assumption of both types of investors (risky and riskless) exhausting all arbitrage opportunities, expected exchange rates should be equal to forward exchange rates. --- # Evidence of UIP <br> For both relationships to hold, these items _must be equal to one another empirically_. -- _In equilibrium_, if investors do not care about risk, then they have no reason to prefer to avoid risk by using the forward market rate. -- Using previous equation, test described as checking whether the .hi-pink[expected rate of depreciation] is equal to the .hi-pink[forward premium] `$$\underbrace{\frac{F_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}{R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}-1}_{\text{Forward Premium}} = \underbrace{\frac{E(F)_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}{R_{\text{USD}/\text{EUR}}}-1}_{\text{Expected Rate of Depreciation}}$$` --- # Evidence of UIP <img src="figures/evidence_uip.png" width="75%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Summary ### Recap * FX market mechanisms in the medium run driven by business cycles * Short run variation in exchange rate attributed to monetary policy and speculation * Parity relationships allow us to identify breakeven points at which investment decisions are made ### Next Time * ExR Systems and single currency areas --- exclude: true