class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide .title[ # EC 380: Lecture 9 ] .subtitle[ ## Trade Policy: International Agreements ] .author[ ### Philip Economides ] .date[ ### Winter 2024 ] --- class: inverse, middle <style type="text/css"> @media print { .has-continuation { display: block !important; } } .pull-lefter { float: left; width: 67%; } .pull-rightish { float: right; width: 25%; } .pull-rightish ~ p { clear: both; } </style> # Prologue --- # Recap <br> ### Previously * Quotas similar to tariffs but yield greater economic losses * Domestic producers tend to prefer quotas to tariffs * Not every non-tariff measure is considered protectionist -- ### Today Trade agreements, joint policy outcomes and assessing recent history with our new knowledge --- # Coordinating Trade Policy <br> Most countries part of .hi-pink[World Trade Organization] and adhere to a default non-discriminatory .hi-pink["Most Favored Nations"] (MFN) tariff rate schedule. -- This .hi-pink[MFN] tariff schedule applies by default to each country within the WTO. -- Exceptions in the use of .hi-pink[regional trade agreements], which apply reduced tariffs to set of parties included in an agreement. -- * Free Trade Agreement -- * Preferential Trade Agreements -- * Customs Unions --- # Free Trade Agreement <br> -- Consists of: * Reduction or elimination of tariffs on qualified -- * Intellectual Property Protection -- * Harmonized Product Standards U.S. has 14 FTAs with 20 countries which comprise about 40 percent of U.S. goods’ exports, with a main goal of .hi-pink[eliminating tariffs] --- # Preferential Trade Agreements <br> Similar to an .hi-pink[FTA] but usually only focuses on the .hi-pink[reduction of tariffs] and covers a .hi-pink[narrower set of products] -- A preferential trade agreement can also just be .hi-pink[unilateral] or for a particular amount of years. -- The US maintains Preferential Trade Agreements with approximately 187 countries. --- # Customs Union <br> Goes a step above and beyond. .hi-pink[Zero tariff rate] among member countries. -- Standardized rates of customs duties on goods imported from other countries * EU is a prevalent example of this system, introduced in 1960s -- UK exit from the European Union and the Customs Union .hi-pink[changed rules] for British businesses doing business in Europe. Rare case of **reversal** of trade liberalization. --- # Creation and Diversion <br> There are notable economic effects of these regional trade agreements -- * Trade increases between countries through .hi-pink[two types] -- * .hi-pink[Trade creation] occurs if member country imports product from other member that it originally produced for itself -- * .hi-pink[Trade diversion] occurs when a member country imports a product from another member that it formerly imported from a country _outside the new trade region_ --- # Creation and Diversion <br> .hi-pink[Trade creation] -- * Consumer surplus gained at home due to importing greater number of goods sold at lower prices -- * Producer surplus gained by exporting country which now sells a greater volume of goods -- * Generates welfare gains to both countries -- Since good was not traded before, these results are directly translatable from .hi-pink[Ricardian] and .hi-pink[HO] model predictions. --- # Creation and Diversion <br> .hi-pink[Trade diversion] -- * Diversion of trade away from country outside of the new trade region -- * Will bring a loss in producer surplus due to reduced export sales -- * May bring losses to countries inside free trade area too in certain cases -- Consider the following numerical example. --- # Creation and Diversion .hi-pink[Numerical Example] -- * Suppose China is currently the US main partner on motor part imports -- * Mexico and the US negotiate a regional trade agreement that lowers tariffs -- * China loses .hi-pink[producer surplus], whereas Mexico gains -- * Mexico may not be the most efficient (lowest-cost) producer of parts -- In fact, we know China was the .hi-pink[most efficient source] due to the precise reliance the US had on China. --- # Creation and Diversion Consider the following table: <table style="width:100%; margin-left: auto; margin-right: auto;" class="table"> <thead> <tr> <th style="text-align:left;"> </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 0% </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 10% </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 20% </th> </tr> </thead> <tbody> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From MEX, before PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From CHN, before PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $19 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From MEX, after PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From CHN, after PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $19 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From the US </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> </tbody> </table> Under this free trade scenario Chinese costs are the lowest, and their goods would be imported --- # Creation and Diversion <br> <table style="width:100%; margin-left: auto; margin-right: auto;" class="table"> <thead> <tr> <th style="text-align:left;"> </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 0% </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 10% </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 20% </th> </tr> </thead> <tbody> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From MEX, before PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From CHN, before PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $19 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20.90 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From MEX, after PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From CHN, after PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $19 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20.90 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From the US </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> </td> </tr> </tbody> </table> -- Under the .hi-pink[10% tariff] scenario, switching into a PTA makes Mexican goods suddenly become the cheapest option. --- # Creation and Diversion <br> <table style="width:100%; margin-left: auto; margin-right: auto;" class="table"> <thead> <tr> <th style="text-align:left;"> </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 0% </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 10% </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> 20% </th> </tr> </thead> <tbody> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From MEX, before PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $24 </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From CHN, before PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $19 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20.90 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22.80 </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From MEX, after PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20 </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From CHN, after PTA </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $19 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $20.90 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22.80 </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> From the US </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> $22 </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> 22 </td> </tr> </tbody> </table> -- PTA keeps Mexican auto part costs fixed at $20. --- # Creation and Diversion <br> .hi-pink[Under 20% tariff MFN], US would have been paying $22 to produce goods domestically. -- .hi-pink[Trade Creation]: Upon forming a PTA, the US collects no tariffs from US importers shipping from Mexico. -- * Switch to Mexican imports at $20 per unit -- * US gains from cost reduction relative to its previous scenario. Mexican exports rise. -- * Chinese welfare neither gains or loses due to lack of pre-existing trade. --- # Creation and Diversion <br> .hi-pink[Under 10% tariff MFN], US would have been paying $20.90 to produce goods using Chinese imports. -- .hi-pink[Trade Diversion]: Upon forming a PTA, the US collects no tariffs from US importers shipping from Mexico. -- * Switch from Chinese to Mexican imports at $20 per unit -- * US gains 90c on lower costs but loses 1.90 in tariff revenue, per unit welfare loss -- * Producer surplus falls in China due to loss of pre-existing trade. --- # Reversal: Brexit -- Voted on in 2016, took 4 years of negotiation to enact. .hi-pink[Effective date]: 31st January 2020 -- So if trade agreements lead to more trade and more trade boosts welfare, why did the UK reverse all the progress it made in .hi-pink[trade liberalization]? -- <img src="figures/bojo_I.jpg" width="70%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Reversal: Brexit -- .hi-pink[How did negotiations go?] -- Huge chaos throughout. UK assumed it would face continued free access to the EU single market due to its economic importance. -- In reality, UK had derived about 13% of its GDP from exports to the EU, while conversely only 3% of the EU’s GDP derived from exports to the UK. -- Although no tariffs are applied to trade, UK exporters have to prove they meet EU standards * Was not previously necessary * Leads to extra charges, taxes, paperwork and the halt of some exports to EU --- # Reversal: Brexit .hi-pink[How did negotiations go?] One major hurdle: .hi-pink[1998 Good Friday (Belfast) Agreement] -- * This earlier international agreement promises to keep open border between Ireland and Northern Ireland * Infeasible if we need border control to check whether goods have appropriate documentation -- * Compromise met by keeping NI in the European Single Market and allowing the Irish Sea to act as a trade border. -- * Goods are checked upon route between NI and rest of the UK. Politically sensitive decision for ardent UK supporters in NI. --- # Reversal: Brexit <br> .hi-pink[What is the UK left with?] -- * Brexit has reduced UK trade openness, foreign direct investment (FDI) inflows, and immigration growth -- * New border frictions and higher transport costs pose new barriers to trade, -- * FDI inflows are unlikely to return to levels reached in the 1990s and 2000s -- * A less diverse workforce and lower FDI levels can also hamper productivity growth --- # Unconventional Hidden Protection <img src="figures/reform_shipping.jpg" width="80%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Unconventional Hidden Protection Recent policy seeks to intervene with containerized trade in the US. Why? -- .pull-left[ <img src="figures/empty_LA.png" width="1381" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] .pull-right[ <img src="figures/empty_NY.png" width="1381" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> ] --- # Unconventional Hidden Protection <br> -- Recently the Biden Administrative has signed into law the .hi-pink[Ocean Shipping Reform Act 2022]. This act features: -- * Punish transport operators charging excessive demmurge fees -- * Penalize companies denying vessel capacity allocations to US exporters -- * Drive up data requirements from transport operators -- All of these policies will translate into higher shipping costs for the average US importer. How would you expect this to affect trade outcomes? -- .hi-pink[Less imports narrow gains from trade.] --- # US and the WTO <br> Trump administration skeptical of dispute settlement procedure of WTO -- * Used several provisions of trade law to apply tariffs that had only been used infrequently in that way -- * Many countries objected to US impositions of tariffs -- * Even before WTO ruling on legitimacy of tariffs, countries responded by applying tariffs to US exports --- # US and the WTO <br> -- Since Dec 10 2019, WTO not able to issue rulings because several judges finished terms and US .hi-pink[blocked appointment of any new judges]. -- Ability of WTO to resolve issues between countries is heavily sensitive to US policitcal atmosphere. -- .hi-pink[Managed Trade]: To resolve these matters and begin lowering tariff rates, US required China nearly double their imports of US goods. -- Given recent epidemic, triggering this kind of adoption of US goods has been .hi-pink[near-impossible to achieve]. --- # US and the WTO -- China bought __none__ of the .hi-pink[additional $200 billion of exports] Trump's deal had promised. -- * Trade war and phase on agreement did little to change China's economic policymaking -- * Beijing intent on becoming more state-centered, less market-oriented -- * With the December 31, 2021 deadline for the $200 billion of purchase commitments now past, US policymakers are seeking a different approach -- * United States working with other major economies, e.g. Trade and Technology Council --- .hi-pink[In Summary] * A variety of trade agreements exist under current international norms * Agreements riddled with uncertainty and not always welfare enhancing * Multi-year negotiations can make or break a domestic economy * Even if policymakers agree multilateral purchase commitments with respect to China, they should learn right lessons from US experiences -- .hi-pink[Next time!] * How do international agreements fare with respect to the environment? --- exclude: true