class: center, middle, inverse, title-slide .title[ # EC 380: Lecture 4 ] .subtitle[ ## Trade Theory: Heckscher-Ohlin (HO) Model ] .author[ ### Philip Economides ] .date[ ### Winter 2024 ] --- class: inverse, middle # Prologue --- # To Recap ### Last Time * Countries with no absolute advantage in production can still trade! -- * Since then, the .hi-pink[internet] and subsequent .hi-pink[information age] have largely narrowed differences in technology -- * .hi-pink[What else helps us understand what drives our need to trade goods?] -- ### Today .hi-slate[Hechscher-Ohlin Model] suggests differences in factor endowments can explain trade patterns --- # Hechscher-Ohlin Model <br> -- We will go with our own version of the model. * Two countries, Home and Foreign * Two goods, steel and cloth * .hi-pink[Two] factors of production, labor and .hi-pink[capital] -- Suppose in our case the home country ends up exporting apple pies and importing potatoes. -- .hi-pink[What would this imply about which good each country has comparative advantage in?] --- # Hechscher-Ohlin Model -- __Key terms:__ -- .hi-slate[Factor abundance]: Relative measure, where if particular factor `\(x\)` represents a large share of total factors, country is `\(x\)`-factor abundant. .hi-slate[Factor scarcity]: Country has less of a particular factor relative to other factors or in comparison to another country. -- The .hi-pink[capital-labor ratio] is a comment tool of comparison for assigning countries into resource endowment groups. -- The higher `\(K/L\)` is for a given country, relative to others, the more capital-abundant it is. --- # Hechscher-Ohlin Model <br> <table class="table" style="margin-left: auto; margin-right: auto;"> <thead> <tr> <th style="text-align:left;"> </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> Ireland </th> <th style="text-align:left;"> United Kingdom </th> </tr> </thead> <tbody> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> Capital </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> 90 Tractors </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> 150 Tractors </td> </tr> <tr> <td style="text-align:left;"> Labor </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> 300 Farmers </td> <td style="text-align:left;"> 400 Farmers </td> </tr> </tbody> </table> -- <br> .hi-pink[Which country is capital-abundant?] -- `$$\frac{K_{IRL}}{L_{IRL}} = 0.3, \ \ \ \frac{K_{UK}}{L_{UK}} = 0.375$$` --- # Hechscher-Ohlin Model ### Production Costs <br> -- The ratio between capital and labor implies .hi-pink[abundancy]. Countries where a given factor is relatively .hi-pink[more abundant] exhibit .hi-pink[lower input prices] per unit of the factor. -- The labor-abundant country finds labor to be relatively cheaper, per unit, than the capital-abundant country. -- HO: Labor-abundant country has a .hi-pink[comparative advantage] due to its edge the cost of production of .hi-pink[labor-intensive goods]. --- # Hechscher-Ohlin Model ### Production Costs <br> -- Since the US is .hi-pink[capital-abundant], it faces relatively cheaper capital and faces a lower opportunity cost in production that uses relatively more capital. -- This may explain US trade patterns in which .hi-pink[capital-intensive] exports of jet engines and agricultural products dominate its goods outflows. --- # Gains from Trade -- <br> Ricardian model assumed a single factor `\(\implies\)` all countries face same trade-off regardless of input levels. -- HO model now considers combinations of factors, where some specific combination of two is most productive. -- .hi-pink[How does this affect our visualization?] Production possibilities frontier (PPF) will be curved instead of straight. --- # New PPF <img src="04-heck-ohlin_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-3-1.svg" width="95%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # New PPF <br> As you can see, adjustments at the tailend of these frontiers require a disproportionately large exchange on equipment. -- Opportunity costs are .hi-pink[rising] for each type of production. -- Each unit increase in the labor-good leads to an increasingly sizeable loss of the other unit. -- .hi-pink[Why?] As you reallocate resources from a capital-intensive good to labor-intensive, you need greater amounts of factors due to factor combinations being misaligned. --- # Gains from Trade: Autarky -- .hi-slate[Closed economy scenario:] Consider a case in which the US does __not__ trade. In absense of trade, Home consumes exactly what it produces. -- <img src="04-heck-ohlin_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-4-1.svg" width="75%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Gains from Trade: Free Trade <br> -- Upon opening up trade and facing no trade costs, the world PPF is now the item of material interest. -- The previous relative prices of goods changes to a .hi-pink[world relative price]. This identifies the slope of the CPC described in IE Ch. 4.2.2. -- Given that this line is not tangental to the production possibility frontier, there are other bundles of goods that reach higher indifference curves `\(U_i\)`. -- In our case, Home reaches `\(U_2\)` by reallocating production away from textiles and towards manufacturing, given that Home is a capital intensive nation. --- # Gains from Trade: Free Trade <img src="04-heck-ohlin_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-5-1.svg" width="95%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Gains from Trade: Free Trade <img src="04-heck-ohlin_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-6-1.svg" width="95%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Gains from Trade: Free Trade <img src="04-heck-ohlin_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-7-1.svg" width="95%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Gains from Trade: Free Trade <img src="04-heck-ohlin_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-8-1.svg" width="95%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> --- # Gains from Trade: Free Trade <br> -- Since we are trading at .hi-pink[world price level], we can reach .hi-pink[higher] indifference curves. -- We .hi-pink[produce at B] and .hi-pink[consume at C] at Home country. -- Therefore if we produce more .hi-pink[manufacuturing output] than we consumer, we must be .hi-pink[exporting] a subset of these goods (difference between B outcome and C outcome). -- In contrast, we produce less .hi-pink[textiles] than we consume, suggesting that Home is .hi-pink[importing] the difference. --- # Comparing to Ricardian Model -- .hi-pink[Why B?] We must produce where the opportunity cost of producing a manufactured good is equal to the relative world price slope (CPC). -- Our notion of trade gains are pretty similar to Ricardian views, but specialization is not complete due to .hi-pink[diminishing marginal productivty] associated with each factor. -- .hi-pink[Diminishing marginal productivty]: Holding your other factor fixed, the marginal unit increase of a given factor yields increasingly smaller contributions to overall output. --- # Comparing to Ricardian Model <img src="04-heck-ohlin_files/figure-html/unnamed-chunk-9-1.svg" width="65%" style="display: block; margin: auto;" /> Imagine having one shovel to share between 5 workers. Sure they can exchange the shovel whenever they get tired, but including 10 more is going to make very little difference to total work output. --- # Trade & Income Distribution -- In .hi-pink[Ricardian model] we ruled out harmful effects and suggest everyone benefits in society. -- Reallocated workers simply left and shrinking industry for an expanding one and were able to exchange their unchanged labor supply for a .hi-pink[larger bundle of goods]. -- The .hi-pink[HO model] takes a more moderate view -- Rather than capital and labor, consider two labor sectors * Skilled * Unskilled Industries require different combinations of skilled and unskilled labor --- # Heterogenous Income Effects <br> -- We will go into this further later into the course but for now keep in mind that trade openness can have heterogeneous effects depending on which part of the skill bracket a laborer belongs to. -- It can be shown that a systematic relationship exists between endowments of factors for a country and who ends up being these winners and losers. -- I'll show you a .hi-pink[theoretical argument] for how this can occur. Later we'll examine .hi-pink[empirical evidence], based on applied econometric analysis. --- # Stolper-Samuelson Theorem <br> Explains theoretical outcomes of assymetric factor outcomes. -- * Income depends on input supplied to value of final product -- * Wages will vary based on their skill level -- * Labor input earnings (wages) demand on their demand and supply -- .hi-pink[Derived demand]: Demand for a good or service that is derived from demand for something else (e.g. demand for labor is based on demand for goods and services). --- # Stolper-Samuelson Theorem <br> Under high output demand, price is high and inputs used to produce benefit by receiving greater returns on their contribution. -- Any change that impacts prices will have direct impacts on outcomes. -- Open trade causes the .hi-pink[export good price] to rise and .hi-pink[import good price] to fall. Demand for each factor readjusts, leading to change in returns to each factor. -- Resources leave sector of imported good and enter sector of exported good, which cause changes in demand for each input in Ricardian model. --- # Stolper-Samuelson Theorem <br> If manufacturing good is the export, demand for capital factor rises and demand for labor factor falls. -- This implies income for actors used intensively for the import sector fall and rises for the intensive factor of the export sector. -- .hi-pink[Stopler-Samuelson Theorem suggests that increase in price of good raises income earned by factors intensively used in its production. Fall in price of goods lowers income of factors used intensively.] --- # Stolper-Samuelson Theorem <br> According to this __theory__, a country with a capital-intensive presence (e.g. USA) will shift away from labor demand. Capital owners will benefit from trade. Laborers will lose out. -- Read further into the .hi-pink[magnification effect]. This may come up in the future. --- # To Recap * Countries with no absolute advantage in production can still trade in both Ricardian and HO models * In HO case, advantages are driven by abundancies in different factors which vary across countries -- * While Ricardian trade openness is a broad gain for everyone, HO highlights a .hi-pink[reallocation] of resources towards specific industries that may disadvantage the factor belonging predominantly to the now partially import-reliant sector. -- ### Next Class * Specific Factors model, Model Empirics & Extensions --- exclude: true