Western University
June 1, 2024
A tax evasion strategy often overlooked by the literature is cost overreporting (Almunia and Lopez-Rodriguez 2018)
Cost overreporting arises when firms acquire false invoices to claim additional tax deductions on value-added (VAT) and corporate income taxes (CIT) (Carrillo et al. 2022)
According to the OECD (“Technology Tools to Tackle Tax Evasion and Tax Fraud” 2017), cost overreporting spreads globally leading to significant tax revenue losses for governments
To address these questions I will use production functions (Olley, Pakes, and Steven 1996; Levinsohn and Petrin 2003; Ackerberg, Caves, and Frazer 2015; Gandhi, Navarro, and Rivers 2020)
Intuitively, output is a function of true inputs; and indirect measure
If we can somehow invert it, the difference between the true inputs and reported inputs is a measure of misreporting
The problem of using production functions to detect tax evasion dealing with productivity
Why is this a problem? Both productivity and misreporting are unobserved and both affect the observed output
Intuitively, for a given level of output, high input utilization might be due to cost overreporting or because of a negative productivity shock
I provide a novel strategy to estimate tax evasion through cost overreporting using production functions
Second, I also formally show that ignoring cost overreporting leads to downward biased productivity and production function parameters
I demonstrate how to recover productivity in the presence of tax evasion
For the sake of time, I will provide evidence of cost overreporting using data from manufacturing firms in Colombia 1981-1986
Roadmap:
We observe output \(Y_{it}\), reported inputs \(K_{it},L_{it}, M_{it}\), and output \(P_t\) and intermediate input prices \(\rho_t\)
Firms overreport their true intermediate inputs \(M_{it}=M^*_{it}\exp(e_{it})\) to evade taxes
We can’t use \(Y_{it}=G(M_{it},K_{it},L_{it})\exp(\omega_{it}+\varepsilon_{it})\)
To fix ideas, assume the production function is Cobb-Douglas,
\[ G(M_{it}, K_{it}, L_{it})\exp(\omega_{it}+\varepsilon_{it})=M^{*\beta}_{it}K_{it}^{\alpha_K}L_{it}^{\alpha_L}\exp(\omega_{it}+\varepsilon_{it}) \]
Using the FOC of the cost-minimization problem of the firm, we can get \[ \ln\left(\frac{\rho_t M_{it}}{P_{t}Y_{it}}\right)+e_{it}=\ln\beta + \ln \mathcal{E}- \varepsilon^Y_{it} \]
In the following, I will use \(s_{it}\equiv \ln\left(\frac{\rho_t M^*_{it}}{P_{t}Y_{it}}\right)+e_{it}\)
Intuitively, changes in incentives to evade taxes will affect \(e\) but not \(\varepsilon\)
I use the 1983 tax reform in Colombia as a natural experiment to identify tax evasion
The Colombian dataset comes from the Annual Survey of Manufacturing (EAM) and contains information about manufacturing firms with more than 10 employees from 1981 to 1991.
Besides the information on output, intermediates, capital, and labor, the dataset includes the type of juridical organization and the sales taxes, and metropolitan area.
Given the changes in sales taxes, it’s natural to think on a diff-in-diff approach, By industry, using Corporations as the control group
However, the reform also affected the CIT, so the result would be ambiguous
Hence, I use a triple-diff approach: Corporations vs Not Corporation vs Exempt Industry
NULL
Missing | Mean | SD | Q1 | Median | Q3 | |
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Sales Taxes | 0 | 0.066 | 0.050 | 0.007 | 0.070 | 0.100 |
Skilled Labor (Wages) | 0 | 0.165 | 17.777 | 0.032 | 0.061 | 0.103 |
Unskilled Labor (Wages) | 0 | 0.177 | 0.358 | 0.073 | 0.140 | 0.233 |
Intermediates | 0 | 0.630 | 0.249 | 0.516 | 0.635 | 0.747 |
Materials + Services | 0 | 0.608 | 0.251 | 0.493 | 0.616 | 0.731 |
Materials + Deductibles | 0 | 0.545 | 0.203 | 0.420 | 0.545 | 0.672 |
Materials | 0 | 0.496 | 0.214 | 0.365 | 0.500 | 0.633 |
Capital | 0 | 0.485 | 7.484 | 0.126 | 0.261 | 0.498 |
Total Expenditure | 0 | 0.203 | 0.425 | 0.104 | 0.167 | 0.258 |
Services | 0 | 0.600 | 0.216 | 0.446 | 0.615 | 0.770 |
Industrial | 0 | 0.243 | 0.201 | 0.088 | 0.186 | 0.344 |
Deductible | 0 | 0.236 | 0.172 | 0.112 | 0.187 | 0.306 |
J. Org. | N | % | ||||
Proprietorship | 5380 | 13.184 | ||||
Ltd. Co. | 25643 | 62.840 | ||||
Corporation | 8324 | 20.398 | ||||
Partnership | 1460 | 3.578 |
\[ \begin{aligned} \max_{M_{it}, e_{it}\in [0,\infty)} [1-q(e_{it}|\theta_{it})]&\left[(P_t\mathbb{E}[Y_{it}]-\rho_{t} M_{it})-\tau\left(P_t\mathbb{E}[Y_{it}]-\rho_{t} (M_{it}+e_{it})\right)\right]\\ +q(e_{it}|\theta_{it})&\left[(1-\tau)(P_t\mathbb{E}[Y_{it}]-\rho_{t} M_{it})-\kappa(e)\right] \\ \text{s.t. }\; Y_{it}=G(M_{it})&\exp(\omega_{it}+\varepsilon_{it}) \end{aligned} \qquad(1)\]
\[ G_M(M_{it})\exp(\omega_{it})\mathcal{E}=\frac{\rho_{t}}{P_t} \qquad(2)\]
Organization | Corporate Income Tax | Liability | Capital | Owners |
---|---|---|---|---|
Corporation | 40% (on distributed dividends) | Limited to capital participation | Tradable capital shares | \(N\ge5\) |
Limited Co. | 20% (on profits) | Limited to capital participation | Non-tradable capital shares | \(2\le N \le 20 (25)\) |
Partnership | 20% (on profits) | Full | Not a capital association | \(N\ge2\) |
Proprietorship | Individual Income Tax | Full | Owner | \(N=1\) |
Reform Year | J.O. Affected | Income Tax Change |
---|---|---|
1983 | Individuals | 8% increase in most scales; Max tax rate was reduced from 56 to 49% |
1983 | Ltd. Co. | Reduction from 20 to 18%; Now subject to presumptive income |
1986 | Individuals | Max tax rate applied was reduced from 49 to 30% |
1986 | Ltd. Co. | Increased from 18 to 30% |
1986 | Corporations | Decreased from 40 to 30% |
P&T (1990) |
|||
---|---|---|---|
Industry Description | Sales Tax Change | SIC | Industry |
Beverages and Tobacco | - to 35;10 | 313 | Beverage Industries |
Beverages and Tobacco | - to 35;10 | 314 | Tobacco Manufactures |
Textiles | 6 to 10 | 321 | Textiles |
Paper | 15 to 10 | 341 | Paper and Paper Products |
Other Chemical Products | 15 to 10 | 351 | Industrial Chemicals |
Soap | 6;15 to 10 | 352 | Other Chemical Products |
Oil and Coal Derivatives | 10 to 14 | 354 | Miscellaneous Products of Petroleum and Coal |
Plastics | 15 to 10 | 356 | Plastic Products Not Elsewhere Classified |
Iron and Steel; Nickel Smelting | 6;15 to 10 | 371 | Iron and Steel Basic Industries |
Equipment and Machinery | 6 to 10 | 382 | Machinery Except Electrical |
Equipment and Machinery | 6 to 10 | 383 | Electrical Machinery Apparatus, Appliances and Supplies |
Transportation | 6 to 10 | 384 | Transport Equipment |
To evaluate the change in tax evasion by input cost overreporting due to the change in the sales tax, I apply a triple difference approach. I use corporations in the industries exempted from sales taxes the year before the policy change as the control group.
Formally, non-corporations in industry \(k\), which might have received an increment or decrement in their sales tax rate,
\[ s_{1,j,t}^k=\lambda^k_t+\mu^k_1+e^{VAT}_{j,t}+e^{CIT}_{j,t}+\varepsilon_{jt} \]
Corporations in industry \(k\), \[ s_{0,j,t}^k=\lambda^k_t+\mu^k_0+\varepsilon_{jt} \]
Likewise, Non-corporations and Corporations in an industry exempt from sales taxes
\[ \begin{aligned} s_{1,j,t}^{E}&=\lambda^{E}_t+\mu^E_1+e^{CIT}_{j,t}+\varepsilon_{jt}\\ s_{0,j,t}^E&=\lambda^E_t+\mu^E_0+\varepsilon_{jt} \end{aligned} \]
Taking the difference between time \(t'\) and \(t\) in industry \(k\) for both, corporations and non-corporations,
\[ \begin{aligned} \mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t'}^k]-\mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t}^k]&=\Delta_\lambda^k+\Delta_e^{VAT}+\Delta_e^{CIT}\\ \mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t'}^k]-\mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t}^k]&=\Delta_\lambda^k \end{aligned} \]
The diff-in-diff method will recover the joint effect of both policy changes, \[ \mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t'}^k]-\mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t}^k]-\left(\mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t'}^k]-\mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t}^k]\right)=\Delta_e^{VAT}+\Delta_e^{CIT} \]
The joint effect might be ambiguous because an increase in the sales tax rate will increase the incentive to overreport inputs cost but a decrease in the CIT might decrease the incentive.
To recover the effect of the change in the sales tax rate, we can use the firms of the industries that are exempted from the sales tax. Intuitively, exempted firms would not react to the change in the sales tax —which is industry-specific—, but only to the CIT —which affects all industries.
So we have,
\[ \begin{aligned} \mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t'}^k]&-\mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t}^k]-\left(\mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t'}^k]-\mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t}^k]\right)\\ &- \left[\mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t'}^{E}]-\mathbb{E}[s_{1,j,t}^{E}]-\left(\mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t'}^{E}]-\mathbb{E}[s_{0,j,t}^{E}]\right)\right]=\Delta_e^{VAT} \end{aligned} \]
In regression form,
\[ s_{jt}=\alpha \left[ \mathbb{1}\{t=t'\}\times\mathbb{1}\{\text{treat}=\text{Non-Corp}\}\times\mathbb{1}\{k\not=E\} \right]+\beta'_ZZ_{jt}+\gamma_j+\gamma_t+\varepsilon_{jt} \]