Western University
May 19, 2023
Acknowledging the strategy’s mechanism (limitation) helps ask better questions that are still of interest and relevant
The identification strategy also works for non-constant elasticities as long as the elasticity is monotonic in the intermediates.
In theory, the identification strategy relies on the subset of non-evaders firms
In practice, identifying the non-evaders subset is non-trivial and depends on the data at hand
However, we can use economic theory, previous empirical evidence, along with the fiscal environment to identify the non-evaders or the subset of firms more likely to be non-evaders
Colombia passed three major fiscal policy changes during this period, in 1983, 1986, and 1990 (Sanchez & Gutierrez, 1994; Gonzalez & Calderon, 2002; Sanchez & Espinoza, 2005; ).
Their main objectives were to increase government tax revenue, decrease tax evasion, and open to foreign markets.
Even though the maximum rate of the progressive tax schedule decreased from 56% to 49%, the 1983 reform expanded the taxpayer base. Taxpayers with income greater than $200,000 COL were now required to report profit taxes.
From 1983 to 1985, the tax authority focused efforts on the 5% biggest taxpayers that represented 80% of the government tax revenue.
With the reform of 1986, the government relocated the tax collection and reception of tax reports to the banking system. The reform also reinforced the control over the big taxpayers.
The 1986 reform decreased the maximum tax rate by 1% annually from 33% in 1986 to 30% in 1989.
In 1983, the VAT increased from 6% to 10%
In 1990, the VAT increased from 10% to 12%
The log share of intermediates’ costs/revenue seems to react according to the fiscal policy changes
In particular, the average log share increases with the 1983 reform (higher VAT, increase taxpayer base)
The growth rate of the tax evasion seems to slow down and then stabilize after the 1986 reform, when the banking system took over the reporting and collecting tax system
The 1990 reform increasing the VAT by 1% seems to have not a significant effect
Previous studies highlight that during most of this period, the evasion of corporate tax and VAT declined
However, the previous analysis could suggest that tax evasion through cost overreporting actually increased from 1984-1987
From previous empirical evidence (Chile: Castellon and Velazques, 2013; Ecuador: Carrillo et al., 2023), the following variables are associated with fake invoicing (positively or negatively correlated):
How does non-established firms overreport with respect established firms?
The data might not even contain the very big firms. Alternatively, we can use the small firms
IE: Fuel, outside work, domestic workers, maintenance
Like finding a discontinuity when we only know the outcome variable
A ranking that identifies the subset of firms that consistently report lower cost share than the average of the rest of the firms over the years
1983: Taxpayer base expand
1986: Reallocation of tax collecting system to banks
Empirical model
\[ \begin{aligned} s_{it}&=\beta_0+\beta_1D(Non-Evaders)+\gamma_J+\varepsilon_{it}^Y\\ s_{it}&=\beta_0+\Phi(k,l,m)+\beta_1D(Non-Evaders)+\gamma_J+\varepsilon_{it}^Y \end{aligned} \qquad(1)\]
Graphs report percentage deviations of Non-Evaders from the rest of the firms, controlling for industry
\(\Delta\%=exp(\beta_1)-1\). Why?
\[ \begin{aligned} \ln\beta_{Non-Evaders}&=\hat{\beta}_0+\hat{\beta}_1\\ &=\ln\beta_{Evaders}+\ln\Delta\\ &=\ln(\beta_{Evaders}\times\Delta)\\ \implies \Delta &=\frac{\beta_{Non-Evaders}}{\beta_{Evaders}}\\ \implies exp(\hat{\beta_1})-1&=\frac{\beta_{Non-Evaders}}{\beta_{Evaders}}-1\\ &\equiv \Delta \% \end{aligned} \]
\[ \begin{aligned} \mathbb{E}\left[\ln\left(\frac{\rho M^*}{PY}\right)\right] &= \mathbb{E}\left[\ln\left(\frac{\partial }{\partial m^*}f(k_{it},l_{it},m_{it}^*+\varepsilon_{it}^M)\right)\right]+\ln\mathcal{E}+\mathbb{E}[\varepsilon_{it}^M] \\ &= \mathbb{E}\left[\ln\left(\frac{\partial }{\partial m^*}f(k_{it},l_{it},m_{it}^*)\right)\right]+\delta+\ln\mathcal{E}+\mathbb{E}[\varepsilon_{it}^M] \end{aligned} \]
where, \(\delta\equiv\mathbb{E}\left[\ln\left(\frac{\partial }{\partial m^*}f(k_{it},l_{it},m_{it}^*+\varepsilon_{it}^M)\right)\right]-\mathbb{E}\left[\ln\left(\frac{\partial }{\partial m^*}f(k_{it},l_{it},m_{it}^*)\right)\right]\)
\(\frac{\partial }{\partial m^*}f(\cdot)\) can still be recovered from compliers
\(\delta\ge0\) if \(\frac{\partial }{\partial m^*}f(k_{it},l_{it},m_{it}^*+\varepsilon_{it}^M)\) is monotonic in \(m_{it}^*+\varepsilon_{it}^M\)
\(\delta\) is a function of \(\varepsilon^M_{it}\) and therefore not independent from \(\mathbb{E}\left[\ln\left(\frac{\partial }{\partial m^*}f(\cdot)\right)\right]\)
CD PF ignores the non-linear effect \(\delta\), however it can be considered a lower bound
The tax evasion may be greater than what CD suggests because \(\delta\ge0\)
Alternatively, because \(m^*_{it}\) is not observed separately from \(\varepsilon_{it}^M\), using a PF with a derivative that is monotonic in \(m_{it}^*+\varepsilon_{it}^M\) might affect estimates of tax evasion
In the case of the translog PF when there is only \(K\) and \(M\)
\[ \begin{aligned} \mathbb{E}\left[\ln\left(\frac{\rho M^*}{PY}\right)\right]=\mathbb{E}&\left[\ln\left(\beta_0 +\beta_K\ln K+\beta_M \ln M^*+\beta_M\varepsilon_{it}^M\right)\right]\\ &+\ln\mathcal{E}+\mathbb{E}[\varepsilon_{it}^M] \end{aligned} \]
Hu et al. (J. Econom. 2022)
\[ \begin{aligned} Y &= m_0(X^*) + \eta\\ X &= X^* + \varepsilon \end{aligned} \]
It is still likely that very large firms do not overreport costs but they might be very few to statistically learn from them
Alternatively, using small firms to learn about tax evasion can provide a lower bound of tax evasion
Empirical model
\[ \begin{aligned} s_{it}&=\beta_0+\beta_1D(Compliers)+\gamma_J+\varepsilon_{it}^Y\\ s_{it}&=\beta_0+\Phi(k,l,m)+\beta_1D(Compliers)+\gamma_J+\varepsilon_{it}^Y \end{aligned} \qquad(2)\]
Graphs report percentage deviations of compliers from the rest of the firms, controlling for industry
\(\Delta\%=exp(\beta_1)-1\). Why?
\[ \begin{aligned} \ln\beta_{Compliers}&=\hat{\beta}_0+\hat{\beta}_1\\ &=\ln\beta_{Evaders}+\ln\Delta\\ &=\ln(\beta_{Evaders}\times\Delta)\\ \implies \Delta &=\frac{\beta_{Compliers}}{\beta_{Evaders}}\\ \implies exp(\hat{\beta_1})-1&=\frac{\beta_{Compliers}}{\beta_{Evaders}}-1\\ &\equiv \Delta \% \end{aligned} \]
Who are the non-evaders? What’s the threshold of size?
Carrillo et al., 2022
Panels A and B show the probability of being a ghost client and the share of firms’reported purchases that are based on receipts from ghost firms, by percentile of firm revenue (for firms that are required to filea purchase annex and have positive revenues)
All industries
All industries
All industries
All manufacturing industries in Colombia, quantiles of different measures
Colombian major manufacturing industries, quantiles of Labor (employee x years)
Colombia, 342 Industry by different measures of size
Conference | Conference Name | Date | Submission | Location |
---|---|---|---|---|
IIO | International Industrial Organization | Mid April | 2023-01-31 | North America |
CEA | Canadian Economics Association | First week June | 2023-02-10 | Canada |
NASM-ES | North America Summer Meeting- Econometrics Society | Mid June | 2023-02-12 | North America |
IAAE | International Association of Applied Economics | Mid June | 2023-02-21 | Mostly Europe |
RIDGE-Public Econ | Research Institute for Development, Growth, and Economics | Mid May | 2023-02-19 | Latin America |
LACEA-LA-ES | Latin American and Caribbean Economic Association | Mid November | 2023-03-30 | Latin America |